The executive deficit of the European Union
Opposition Leader Margaret Thatcher shows her European colours in Parliament Square, June 1975. PA Archive/ Press Association. All rigths reserved.Not
even the enormity of the recent terrorist attacks in Brussels has managed to
shake national and European leaders out of their political torpor. In every
statement they make there is a mantra, which is heard over and over again: ‘we
must improve coordination among the national security and intelligence systems’.
The same mantra was repeated at the peak of the euro crisis, and is still used
in the face of the arrival of millions of migrants to our continent. The
keyword of the mantra is always the same: coordination.
Faced
with crises and threats of historical proportions, what the member states of
the European Union (EU) are willing to do is, wait for it, coordinate better. In
other words, they are prepared to cooperate, provided, however, that each
national government maintains control over its own domestic policies. This is
the problem that goes unaddressed and so creates all the other problems: we
have a Union but we don’t have a government of the Union.
The EU’s executive power: uncertain, dispersed and
opaque
Not
even the enormity of the recent terrorist attacks in Brussels has managed to
shake national and European leaders out of their political torpor. The
EU suffers primarily from a deficit of executive power. Its executive power is
uncertain, dispersed, and opaque. It is uncertain because it is ascribed both
to the European Council of heads of state and government and to the European Commission.
However, on the politically most important issues for the member states, it is
the European Council that controls the political initiative.
Since
crises keep rolling in, the European Council, which under the Treaties should
meet twice a year, is de facto in permanent
sitting (between February and March 2016, for instance, it met formally and
informally three times). Thus, Europe’s heads of government cannot follow
domestic politics as they would like, but at the same time they do not have the
resources to conduct European affairs as they should. The uncertainty about who
must decide is inevitable.
The
EU’s executive power is also dispersed. The European Council consists of 28 heads
of state and government, plus its semi-permanent president, the president of
the Commission, and the High Representative for Foreign Affairs and Security
Policy whenever international issues are on the agenda. This amounts to 30 or 31
political leaders, each with a domestic agenda and outlook, and each worried
about the domestic consequences of collegial decisions. If things go well, an
agreement is found and the ground rule is consensus. However, when things go
wrong, the game changes: everyone tries to impose, or in any case preserve, his
or her own national interest.
As
if that were not enough, the European Council has no administrative support
structure. It must therefore rely on the Commission, but above all on the
Council of Ministers. The latter, which should be a legislative body, thus also
contributes to executive decisions (as in the case of ECOFIN and the Eurogroup),
so generating a confusion of powers which would make Baron Montesquieu weep. The February 2016 deal
between the European Council and the British government is a clear example of
the double game played by the national leaders of the EU member states.
Additionally,
the Commission consists of 28 commissioners. Between one and the other there is
then the never-ending committee system. Considering the members of the European
Council, the Commission and the various formations of the Council of Ministers,
the conclusion is that almost one hundred people (but not always the same
people) formally share decision-making powers in Brussels for each crucial
issue – this without taking into account that many decisions also see the involvement
of the president of the European Central Bank as well as members of the
European Parliament.
Finally,
the executive power of the EU is opaque. To be sure, all the executive powers
of democracies are protected by confidentiality (while this is not the case for
the work of legislative assemblies). Opaqueness, however, should be understood here
in the sense of making decisions (or non-decisions) for which no one is held to
account – i.e. for which no one is responsible.
This
opaqueness reaches its apex in the case of the European Council which can,
overnight, transform itself from a formal institution of the EU into an
international conference of the member states, thus making decisions according
to international rather than EU law. The February 2016 deal between the
European Council and the British government is a clear example of the double
game played by the national leaders of the EU member states.
Coordination is not enough
How,
then, can one imagine resolving the EU’s decision-making deficit with “better coordination”,
when that deficit is due exactly to the logic of coordination among national
governments? To handle the financial, migration and terrorism crisis, a common
government of the Union is needed. A limited government, to be sure, but still
equipped with autonomous resources and skills, with its own democratic
legitimacy, and thus kept in check by a separate legislative power. This goes
well beyond the simple idea of better coordination of the existing system. It
is necessary to create in Brussels a true executive power with its own intelligence
and investigative system, its system of control of the external frontiers of
the Union, and its own military force.
Likewise,
it is necessary that this executive power be equipped with its own budget, supported
by a fiscal capacity independent of the financial transfers made by the member
states, to be used on the basis of political considerations (while currently
expenditures are pre-established by interstate negotiations).
Coordination
is not enough to beat the terrorist criminal organizations that have killed
hundreds and hundreds of innocent people. It is necessary to create executive
institutions that can operate at the same level as the challenges they face – which
are European and no longer national.
Rationalizing dualism
How
is it possible to resolve the Union’s deficit of executive power? The main
alternative to the current intergovernmental coordination continues to be the parliamentary
model. The Commission should become the exclusive executive power of the Union,
and operate on the basis of support by a majority of the European Parliament.
The Commission president, moreover, should also have the role of president of
the European Council. This is certainly a plausible alternative to the current
state of affairs, one coherent with the political tradition of executive
democratization in the majority of European nation-states.
However,
it is unlikely that this alternative would be accepted by the leaders of
countries with the historical and political import of EU member states. It is therefore
necessary to try a new approach, namely democratizing and rationalizing the dualism
that Europe’s executive power already embodies.
At
its head there should be, on the one hand, a president of the Union who grounds
his/her legitimacy in the EU member states and, on the other, a president of
the Commission who is legitimized by the European Parliament. The former should
have a political role, the latter an operational one. It is through this executive
dualism that the EU’s decision-making process must be institutionalized. And
this must be done quickly – because, as with every political body, a EU which
cannot decide has no future.
This article is published as part of an openDemocracy editorial partnership with EuVisions, an online observatory on social Europe established within the ERC-funded REScEU project, based at the University of Milan and the Centro Einaudi of Turin.